Page 104 - Acharya Vinoba Bhave in 21st Century ISBN
P. 104

21oha “krkCnh esa vkpk;Z fouksck Hkkos dh izklafxdrk






               not conceptual thought. I would try to bring out their features by placing them in their historical context
               and showing how they developed before they were swamped by the bhoodan movement. I guessed I

               would not find much current interest in the concepts—I had heard of none myself and I presumed
               abolishing money and farming-by-hand could have little relevance for life today. I expected to be able

               to conclude that the brochure for this seminar was mistaken in suggesting the concepts could still have
               relevance for today and help revive interest in Vinoba.

                       As I point out above, the sudden appearance of kânchan-mukti as a way of identifying with the
               poor and preparing the way for non-violence seems to spring from nowhere. This makes historians

               uncomfortable. Perhaps more research will erase the mystery, but for now, kânchan-mukti seems like
               an idea run wild. It may be rooted in the asceticism of the bhikshu, but such asceticism was limited—

               it never applied to most people and the bhikshu did not labor for his alms. Vinoba recognized no limits.
               First he extended the idea to his ashram, as an experiment; then, before there was time for a real test,

               he was recommending it to other Gandhian institutions; and then to society at large. This is not careful
               experimentation or a scientific attitude. One wonders if he really expected many to follow.

                       There were two reasons, I think, why kânchan-mukti was bound to fail. The first is that it
               departed too radically from Gandhi. While others might admire Vinoba’s spiritual effort, they saw no

               reason to follow his practice when it meant hard physical work, greater privation, and leaving aside the
               good work they were already doing. If Gandhi was satisfied with spinning and some household chores

               as bread labor, they were too. And Gandhi had no real issues with money: he collected it in huge
               amounts and spent it creatively and responsibly without regrets. To counter the criticism that his position

               on money was not Gandhi’s position, Vinoba would invoke swaraj, saying now that we had swaraj, the
               situation was different and demanded that we do more to demonstrate our faith. Exactly what difference

               swaraj made was never clear.
                       The second reason kânchan-mukti was bound to fail is that it was bad economics and quite out

               of step with the times. This is not the place to go into the limitations of “Gandhian economics,” but
               Vinoba shared these and added more of his own. For him money was intrinsically dirty, something to

               be avoided. It was also artificial, fake, a shyster, unrelated to real value and a mechanism for cheating
               people. Despite the best efforts of modern economists, Vinoba could not see money as a convenient

               medium of exchange that brought incredible benefits along with its potential for abuse. To believe that
               the world would be better off without it, one has to accept a simple and very local agrarian life where

               people are content with basic shelter, food, and clothing. Vinoba seemed willing to accept that; the
               great majority of people were not.

                       I sometimes wonder what might have happened had someone successfully explained to Vinoba
               what a marvel of cooperation and trust among people money really is. If he could have seen that aspect








                                                           104
   99   100   101   102   103   104   105   106   107   108   109